improved notes on lecture 17
This commit is contained in:
parent
28bc88cbc5
commit
b7e2d7bd3c
1 changed files with 86 additions and 42 deletions
|
@ -8,6 +8,12 @@
|
|||
variables $(X_t)_{t \in T}$ for some index set $T$.
|
||||
In this lecture we will consider the case $T = \N$.
|
||||
\end{definition}
|
||||
\begin{definition}[Previsible process]
|
||||
Consider a filtration $(\cF_n)_{n \ge 0}$.
|
||||
A stochastic process $(C_n)_{n \ge 1}$
|
||||
is called \vocab[Stochastic process!previsible]{previsible},
|
||||
iff $C_n$ is $\cF_{n-1}$-measurable.
|
||||
\end{definition}
|
||||
|
||||
\begin{goal}
|
||||
What about a ``gambling strategy''?
|
||||
|
@ -19,30 +25,52 @@
|
|||
Suppose that there is another stochastic process
|
||||
$(C_n)_{n \ge 1}$ such that $C_n$ is determined
|
||||
by the information gathered up until time $n$,
|
||||
i.e.~$C_n$ is measurable with respect to $\cF_{n-1}$.
|
||||
If such process $C_n$ exists, we say that $ C_n$ is
|
||||
\vocab[Stochastic process!previsible]{previsible}.
|
||||
i.e.~$C_n$ is previsible.
|
||||
Think of $C_n$ as our strategy of playing the game.
|
||||
Then $C_n(X_n - X_{n-1})$ defines the win in the $n$-th game,
|
||||
while
|
||||
\[
|
||||
\begin{equation}
|
||||
Y_n \coloneqq \sum_{j=1}^n C_j(X_j - X_{j-1})
|
||||
\]
|
||||
\label{eqn:cumulative-win-process}
|
||||
\end{equation}
|
||||
defines the cumulative win process.
|
||||
\end{goal}
|
||||
\begin{lemma}
|
||||
\label{lem:gambling-strategy}
|
||||
If $(C_n)_{n \ge 1}$ is previsible and $(X_n)_{n \ge 0}$
|
||||
is a (sub/super-) martingale
|
||||
is a martingale
|
||||
and there exists a constant $K_n$ such that $|C_n(\omega)| \le K_n$.
|
||||
Then $(Y_n)_{n \ge 1}$ is also a (sub/super-) martingale.
|
||||
Then $(Y_n)_{n \ge 1}$ defined in \eqref{eqn:cumulative-win-process}
|
||||
is also a martingale.
|
||||
\end{lemma}
|
||||
\begin{proof}
|
||||
Exercise. \todo{Copy Exercise 10.4}
|
||||
\end{proof}
|
||||
\begin{remark}
|
||||
The assumption of $K_n$ being constant can be weakened to
|
||||
$C_n \in L^p(\bP)$, $X_n \in ^q(\bP)$ with $\frac{1}{p} + \frac{1}{q} = 1$.
|
||||
$C_n \in L^p(\bP)$, $X_n \in L^q(\bP)$ with $\frac{1}{p} + \frac{1}{q} = 1$.
|
||||
|
||||
If $C_n \ge 0$ the assumption of $(X_n)_{n\ge 0}$
|
||||
being a martingale can be weakened to it being
|
||||
a sub-/supermartingale.
|
||||
Then $(Y_n)_{n \ge 1}$ is a sub-/supermartingale as well.
|
||||
\end{remark}
|
||||
\begin{refproof}{lem:gambling-strategy}
|
||||
It is clear that $Y_n$ is $\cF_n$-measurable.
|
||||
Suppose that $C_n \in L^p(\bP)$ and $X_n \in L^{q}(\bP)$
|
||||
for all $n$.
|
||||
We have
|
||||
\begin{IEEEeqnarray*}{rCl}
|
||||
\|Y_n\|_{L^1}
|
||||
&\le& \sum_{i=1}^{n} \|C_i(X_i - X_{i-1})\|_{L^1}\\
|
||||
&\overset{\text{Hölder}}{\le}& \sum_{i=1}^{n} \|C_i\|_{L^p} \|(X_i - X_{i-1})\|_{L^q} \\
|
||||
&<&\infty
|
||||
\end{IEEEeqnarray*}
|
||||
and
|
||||
\begin{IEEEeqnarray*}{rCl}
|
||||
\bE[Y_{n+1} - Y_n | \cF_n]
|
||||
&=& \bE[C_{n+1} (X_{n+1} - X_n) | \cF_n]\\
|
||||
&=& C_{n+1} (\bE[X_{n+1} | \cF_n] - X_n)\\
|
||||
&=& 0.
|
||||
\end{IEEEeqnarray*}
|
||||
\end{refproof}
|
||||
|
||||
Suppose we have $(X_n)$ adapted, $X_n \in L^1(\bP)$,
|
||||
$(C_n)_{n \ge 1}$ previsible.
|
||||
|
@ -51,21 +79,29 @@ Pick two real numbers $a < b$.
|
|||
Wait until $X_n \le a$, then start playing.
|
||||
Stop playing when $X_n \ge b$.
|
||||
I.e.~define
|
||||
\begin{itemize}
|
||||
\item $C_1 \coloneqq 0$,
|
||||
\item $C_n \coloneqq \One_{\{C_{n-1} = 1\}} \cdot \One_{\{X_{n-1} \le b\}} + \One_{\{C_{n-1} = 0\} } \One_{\{X_{n-1} < a\}}$.
|
||||
\end{itemize}
|
||||
|
||||
\begin{equation}
|
||||
\begin{aligned}
|
||||
C_1 &\coloneqq 0,\\
|
||||
C_n &\coloneqq
|
||||
\One_{\{C_{n-1} = 1\}} \cdot \One_{\{X_{n-1} \le b\}}
|
||||
+ \One_{\{C_{n-1} = 0\} } \One_{\{X_{n-1} < a\}}.
|
||||
\end{aligned}
|
||||
\label{eqn:upcrossing-strategy}
|
||||
\end{equation}
|
||||
|
||||
\begin{definition}
|
||||
Fix $N \in \N$ and let
|
||||
\[U_n^X([a,b]) \coloneqq \# \{\text{Upcrossings of $[a,b]$ made by $n \mapsto X_n(\omega)$ by time $n$}\},\]
|
||||
i.e.~$U_n([a,b])(\omega)$ is the largest $k \in \N_0$ such that we can find a
|
||||
\[U_N^X([a,b]) \coloneqq \# \{\text{Upcrossings of $[a,b]$ made by $n \mapsto X_n(\omega)$ by time $N$}\},\]
|
||||
i.e.~$U_N([a,b])(\omega)$ is the largest $k \in \N_0$ such that we can find a
|
||||
sequence
|
||||
$0 \le s_1 < t_1 < s_2 < t_2 < \ldots < s_k < t_k \le N$
|
||||
such that $X_{s_j}(\omega) < a$ and $X_{t_j}(\omega) > b$ for all $1 \le j \le k$.
|
||||
\end{definition}
|
||||
Clearly $U_N^X([a,b]) \uparrow$ as $N$ increases.
|
||||
It follows that the monotonic limit $U_\infty([a,b]) \coloneqq \lim_{N \to \infty} U_N([a,b])$ exists pointwise.
|
||||
It follows that the monotonic limit
|
||||
\[U_\infty([a,b]) \coloneqq \lim_{N \to \infty} U_N([a,b])\]
|
||||
exists pointwise.
|
||||
\begin{lemma} % Lemma 1
|
||||
\label{lec17l1}
|
||||
\[
|
||||
|
@ -74,31 +110,37 @@ It follows that the monotonic limit $U_\infty([a,b]) \coloneqq \lim_{N \to \inf
|
|||
\{\omega: U^{Z}_\infty([a,b])(\omega) = \infty\}
|
||||
\]
|
||||
for every sequence of measurable functions $(Z_n)_{n \ge 1}$.
|
||||
|
||||
\end{lemma}
|
||||
\begin{lemma} % 2
|
||||
\label{lec17l2}
|
||||
Let $Y_n(\omega) \coloneqq \sum_{j=1}^n C_j(X_j - X_{j-1})$.
|
||||
Let $Y_n(\omega) \coloneqq \sum_{j=1}^n C_j(X_j - X_{j-1})$,
|
||||
where $C_n $ is defined as in \eqref{eqn:upcrossing-strategy}
|
||||
Then \[Y_N \ge (b -a) U_N([a,b]) - (X_N - a)^{-}.\]
|
||||
\end{lemma}
|
||||
\begin{proof}
|
||||
Every upcrossing of $[a,b]$ increases the value of $Y$ by $(b-a)$,
|
||||
while the last intverval of play $(X_n -a)^{-}$ overemphasizes the loss.
|
||||
while the last interval of play $(X_n -a)^{-}$ overemphasizes the loss.
|
||||
\end{proof}
|
||||
|
||||
\begin{lemma} %3
|
||||
\label{lec17l3}
|
||||
Suppose $(X_n)_n$ is a supermartingale.
|
||||
Then in the above setup
|
||||
\[(b-a) \bE[U_N([a,b])] \le \bE[(X_n - a)^-].\]
|
||||
\[(b-a) \bE[U_N([a,b])] \le \bE[(X_N - a)^-].\]
|
||||
\end{lemma}
|
||||
\begin{proof}
|
||||
This is obvious from \autoref{lec17l2}
|
||||
and the supermartingale property.
|
||||
Since $C_n \ge 0$,
|
||||
by \autoref{lem:gambling-strategy} we have that $Y_n$ is a supermartingale.
|
||||
Hence $\bE[Y_N] \le \bE[Y_1] = 0$.
|
||||
From \autoref{lec17l2} it follows that
|
||||
\[
|
||||
(b-a) \bE[U_N([a,b])] \le \bE[Y_n] + \bE[(X_N-a)^-] \le \bE[(X_N-a)^-].
|
||||
\]
|
||||
|
||||
\end{proof}
|
||||
\begin{corollary}
|
||||
Let $(X_n)_n$ be a
|
||||
\vocab[Supermartingale!bounded]{supermartingale bounded in $L^1(\bP)$},
|
||||
\vocab[Supermartingale!bounded in $L^1$]{supermartingale bounded in $L^1(\bP)$},
|
||||
i.e.~$\sup_n \bE[|X_n|] < \infty$.
|
||||
Then $(b-a) \bE(U_\infty) \le |a| + \sup_n \bE(|X_n|)$.
|
||||
In particular, $\bP[U_\infty = \infty] = 0$.
|
||||
|
@ -110,12 +152,21 @@ It follows that the monotonic limit $U_\infty([a,b]) \coloneqq \lim_{N \to \inf
|
|||
Since $U_N(\cdot) \ge 0$ and $U_N(\cdot ) \uparrow U_\infty(\cdot )$,
|
||||
by the monotone convergence theorem
|
||||
\[
|
||||
\bE(U_n([a,b])] \uparrow \bE[U_\infty([a,b])].
|
||||
\bE(U_N([a,b])] \uparrow \bE[U_\infty([a,b])].
|
||||
\]
|
||||
\end{proof}
|
||||
|
||||
Assume now, that our process $(X_n)_{n \ge 1}$ is a supermartingale
|
||||
Let us now consider the case that our process $(X_n)_{n \ge 1}$ is a supermartingale
|
||||
bounded in $L^1(\bP)$.
|
||||
|
||||
\begin{theorem}[Doob's martingale convergence theorem]
|
||||
\label{doobmartingaleconvergence}
|
||||
\label{doob}
|
||||
Any supermartingale bounded in $L^1$ converges almost surely to a
|
||||
random variable, which is almost surely finite.
|
||||
In particular, any non-negative supermartingale converges a.s.~to a finite random variable.
|
||||
\end{theorem}
|
||||
\begin{refproof}{doobmartingaleconvergence}
|
||||
Let
|
||||
\[
|
||||
\Lambda \coloneqq \{\omega | X_n(\omega) \text{ does not converge to anything in $[-\infty,\infty]$}\}.
|
||||
|
@ -127,10 +178,11 @@ We have
|
|||
&=& \bigcup_{a,b \in \Q} \underbrace{\{\omega | \liminf_N X_N(\omega) < a < b < \limsup_N X_N(\omega)\}}_{\Lambda_{a,b}} \\
|
||||
\end{IEEEeqnarray*}
|
||||
|
||||
We have $\Lambda_{a,b} \subseteq \{\omega : U_{\infty}([a,b])(\omega) = \infty\} $ by lemma 1. % TODO REF
|
||||
By lemma 3 % TODO REF
|
||||
we have $\bP(\Lambda_{a,b}) = 0$, hence $\bP(\Lambda) = 0$.
|
||||
Hence there exists a random variable $X_\infty$ such that $X_n \xrightarrow{a.s.} X_\infty$.
|
||||
We have $\Lambda_{a,b} \subseteq \{\omega : U_{\infty}([a,b])(\omega) = \infty\}$
|
||||
by \autoref{lec17l1}.
|
||||
By \autoref{lec17l3} we have $\bP(\Lambda_{a,b}) = 0$,
|
||||
hence $\bP(\Lambda) = 0$.
|
||||
Thus there exists a random variable $X_\infty$ such that $X_n \xrightarrow{a.s.} X_\infty$.
|
||||
|
||||
\begin{claim}
|
||||
$\bP[X_\infty \in \{\pm \infty\}] = 0$.
|
||||
|
@ -146,14 +198,7 @@ Hence there exists a random variable $X_\infty$ such that $X_n \xrightarrow{a.s.
|
|||
\end{IEEEeqnarray*}
|
||||
\end{subproof}
|
||||
|
||||
We have thus shown
|
||||
\begin{theorem}[Doob's martingale convergence theorem]
|
||||
\label{doobmartingaleconvergence}
|
||||
\label{doob}
|
||||
Any supermartingale bounded in $L^1$ converges almost surely to a
|
||||
random variable, which is almost surely finite.
|
||||
In particular, any non-negative supermartingale converges a.s.~to a finite random variable.
|
||||
\end{theorem}
|
||||
|
||||
The second part follows from
|
||||
\begin{claim}
|
||||
Any non-negative supermartingale is bounded in $L^1$.
|
||||
|
@ -163,5 +208,4 @@ The second part follows from
|
|||
Since the supermartingale is non-negative, we have $\bE[|X_n|] = \bE[X_n]$
|
||||
and since it is a supermartingale $\bE[X_n] \le \bE[X_0]$.
|
||||
\end{subproof}
|
||||
|
||||
\todo{rearrange proof}
|
||||
\end{refproof}
|
||||
|
|
Reference in a new issue